Interest rates are negative. Is the economy crashing?

by Fabius Maximus

Summary: Interest rates have again plunged to near-zero and even below zero rates in some nations. Doomsters predict horrific consequences. But the long-dead financiers who built the British Empire advise us to stay cool, and look to history and economic theory for reassurance. It shows we have entered a new world in our new century.

A graph of interest rates on investment-grade bonds, US and foreign.

BofA-Merrill Graph of Global Interest Rates

Interest rates are falling fast in the US and have gone below zero in many markets around the world. As with all unusual phenomena, doomsters warn that this means disaster – or even that it will cause an apocalypse.

This is more evidence that, as I have been describing since 2003, that we are entering a new economic regime – the inevitable and irresistible evolution of the global economy in a changing world. Like all futures, it is a new combination of things from the past. As for Interest rates, they have been negative in the past without damaging the economy. But swings to extreme rates, high or low, can painfully destabilize financial markets. Unfortunately, we cannot predict which markets – or when. History shows that even market crashes need not wreck the real economy.

This essay by Andrew Odlyzko, one of our era’s top polymaths and futurists, gives us a new perspective on the economy and its markets by comparing them with those of Victorian England. Insights like this can help us better understand what is happening and what lies ahead.

Leadenhall Street in the City of London
Leadenhall Street in London. By Thomas Hosmer Shepherd (1837). From Wikimedia Commons.

What would surprise early Victorian market players
if they came alive today?

By Andrew Odlyzko in the LSE Business Review, 30 September 2016.

“Perhaps the greatest surprise would be the combination of high equity prices and low long-term interest rates.”

What would early Victorians make of today’s markets? Such questions are more than just idle curiosities. For example, the recent wide acceptance around the world of negative interest rates was a surprise. Why didn’t the money go into cash? Yet observers should not have been startled by this development. In Britain in the early 1850s, Exchequer Bills effectively offered negative rates. The convenience of those paper instruments gave them higher value than stacks of gold coins, just as today the convenience of electronic ledger balances is worth something compared to having to handle containers full of banknotes.

The Exchequer Bills episode is just one minor finding from recent studies that integrate data from the ledgers in the Bank of England Archive with price reports, press coverage, and other sources. Previously unknown statistics about completeness of price reports, turnover rates, and dealer activity have been obtained. It has also been found that the London Stock Exchange was a key part of the “shadow banking system” of the time.

We are primarily funded by readers. Please subscribe and donate to support us!

Aside from statistics, we can also obtain some qualitative insights about modern finance from these investigations. Our basic laws and institutions are clear linear descendants of those created at that time.

If some of those early Victorians were to come alive today, they would have no difficulty recognising all the modern financial instruments and services, although they would surely marvel at such concoctions as CDO squareds. Many current concerns would be familiar to them as well. While they did not talk about climate change, they did worry about natural resource depletion, and the effects of globalisation.

Queen Victoria by Franz Xaver Winterhalter (1859)
Queen Victoria by Franz Xaver Winterhalter (1859).

Inequality was even greater than today. Deflation and the analogue of our “Great Savings Glut” were visible, and seemed natural. The terms secular stagnation and liquidity trap had not yet been invented, but they corresponded to widely held attitudes.

Although the financial system was far smaller than today, public opinions about it were not dissimilar. Respect was often mixed with fear and loathing, as in an 1850 magazine article that called the London Stock Exchange “an institution destitute of moral principle, but at the same time omnipotent in its influence upon the moral and social condition of nations {source here}.”

So what would surprise those early Victorian observers the most, were they to come alive today? One candidate would surely be our touching acceptance of financial innovation as socially productive. Another would be our faith in central planning, in the presumed ability of policy makers to ensure smooth and steady growth. The Minsky Instability Hypothesis would be regarded as obviously true.

What we find in the 19th century are opinions, such as that of The Times {on 14 May 1866}, that crashes occur about once a decade, and that they lead people to “the reflection that they are at least the wiser for it, that they will not be taken in a second time,” and yet “the next fit comes on them like the rest, and they go through all the stages of the disease with pathological accuracy.”

The Efficient Market Hypothesis would seem to the early Victorians as amusing, but a fantasy. They understood that some semblance of efficiency could be achieved, but only through diligent efforts of experienced traders. And even those traders could not always control market irrationalities, and were themselves subject to limitations of groupthink.

Perhaps the greatest and hardest to accept surprise in modern markets would be the combination of high equity prices and low long term interest rates. Today’s commentators regard this as natural, and keep reassuring investors that low interest rates help sustain record-high corporate profits, which justify the high share prices.

There is certainly evidence that in the short run, low interest rates do boost profits. But on a long scale, basic economic logic says that interest rate and profits should move the same way. After all, bonds and equity are just different ways to fund ventures, and interest and profits are the cost of capital. There is a difference between the two, reflecting different risks. But there should be a strong positive correlation. And that is how the early Victorians thought about it. The theoretician Robert Hamilton wrote about it in the 1810s.

So did James Morrison, one of the richest merchant bankers of that era, in the 1840s. And so did others. Were they to come alive today, they would surely be astounded. They would wonder why, if Lloyd Blankfein, the head of Goldman Sachs, was indeed “doing God’s work,” why was he not mobilising all that low-cost money lying around in order to compete away the extravagantly high equity returns? And they would surely conjecture that once capitalism started working properly again, this anomaly would disappear, and either bond or share prices (or both) would crash.

Notes.

 

 

Views:

Leave a Comment

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.